Lexploria - Legal research enhanced by smart algorithms
Lexploria beta Legal research enhanced by smart algorithms
Menu
Browsing history:

WASA Ömsesidigt, Försäkringsbolaget Valands Pensionsstiftelse, a group of approximately 15000 individuals v. SWEDEN

Doc ref: 13013/87 • ECHR ID: 001-319

Document date: December 14, 1988

  • Inbound citations: 24
  • Cited paragraphs: 0
  • Outbound citations: 8

WASA Ömsesidigt, Försäkringsbolaget Valands Pensionsstiftelse, a group of approximately 15000 individuals v. SWEDEN

Doc ref: 13013/87 • ECHR ID: 001-319

Document date: December 14, 1988

Cited paragraphs only



AS TO THE ADMISSIBILITY OF

Application No. 13013/87

by Wasa Liv Ömsesidigt,

Försäkringsbolaget Valands Pensionsstiftelse

and a group of approximately 15,000 individuals

against Sweden

        The European Commission of Human Rights sitting in private on

14 December 1988, the following members being present:

                MM.  C.A. NØRGAARD, President

                     J.A. FROWEIN

                     S. TRECHSEL

                     G. SPERDUTI

                     E. BUSUTTIL

                     G. JÖRUNDSSON

                     A.S. GÖZÜBÜYÜK

                     A. WEITZEL

                     J.C. SOYER

                     H.G. SCHERMERS

                     H. VANDENBERGHE

                Mrs.  G.H. THUNE

                Sir  Basil HALL

                MM.  F. MARTINEZ

                     C.L. ROZAKIS

                Mrs.  J. LIDDY

                Mr.  H.C. KRÜGER, Secretary to the Commission

        Having regard to Article 25 of the Convention for the

Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms;

        Having regard to the application introduced on 15 June 1987

by Wasa Liv Ömsesidigt, Försäkringsbolaget Valands Pensionsstiftelse

and a group of approximately 15,000 individuals against Sweden and

registered on 15 June 1987 under file No. 13013/87;

        Having regard to the report provided for in Rule 40 of the

Rules of Procedure of the Commission;

        Having deliberated;

        Decides as follows:

THE FACTS

        The facts of the case, as submitted by the applicants, may be

summarised as follows:

        The first applicant, Wasa Liv Ömsesidigt, is a Swedish mutual

life insurance company with its headquarters in Stockholm.  The second

applicant, Försäkringsbolaget Valands Pensionsstiftelse, is a Swedish

pension foundation also with its headquarters in Stockholm.  The third

applicant is a group of approximately 15.000 Swedish and non-Swedish

nationals holding pension and endowment insurance policies in the

first and second applicant companies.  Before the Commission the

applicants are represented by Mr.  Dag Wersén of the law firm Lagerlöf

in Stockholm.

        The application concerns the introduction in Sweden of a new

legislation in December 1986 imposing a once and for all property tax

on life insurance companies, certain friendly societies and pension

foundations (Lag om tillfällig förmögenhetsskatt för

livsförsäkringsbolag, understödsföreningar och pensionsstiftelser).

The relationship between on the one hand the first and second

applicant and on the other hand the third applicant

        One of the various pension systems available in Sweden is the

buying of a private pension policy from a private life insurance

company.  Such policies do not follow any social insurance index but

the future value of the policies depends exclusively upon successful

administration of the premium income received.  The greater part of

such insurance is contracted by private individuals wishing to improve

their pension status.  This category includes private employees

requiring a better pension than they can expect from the national

social insurance scheme as well as businessmen and farmers who have to

arrange their service pensions themselves.  In addition to the above

groups there are people who are not in need of any additional pension

themselves but want to make provision for their survivors in case of

their death.  Furthermore, life insurance is generally also a

long-range kind of saving.

        In Sweden, licensing and forms of life insurance business are

governed by the Insurance Companies Act of 1982 (försäkringsrörelselag

(1982:713)).

        Licensing (in the form of a concession) by the Government is

mandatory for carrying on life insurance business.  A concession

includes official confirmation of the company's charter and the

general rules for the life insurance business.

        The general rules of a life insurance company can be regarded

as a legal supplement to the company's charter.  They are also

essential for the contractual relationship between the company and its

policyholders.  In most cases the general insurance conditions of

life insurance policies contain an explicit provision which makes the

general rules, applying at any time, an integral part of the insurance

agreement.

        As a general principle of Swedish insurance law, all life

insurance business must be operated solely in the interest of the

policyholders.  As a consequence all profits have to be allotted to

the policyholders in the form of a bonus.  Dividends to shareholders

and similar payments are not allowed.

        As a consequence of the said general principle most life

insurance companies in Sweden are operated in mutual form - i.e. the

companies are owned by the policyholders.  There is, however, no rule

against carrying on life insurance business in the form of a joint

stock company.  However, no dividends may in this case be paid to

shareholders.  Consequently, there is in practice virtually no

difference between the company forms for life insurance business.  The

business is always operated in accordance with mutual principles and

solely in the interests of the policyholders.

        The fact that all insurance companies are effectively operated

on a mutual basis does not mean that the policyholders have any legal

claim to direct ownership of the companies' assets as such.  All

property - shares, bonds, real estate etc. - in which the companies

invest their funds is the company's own property as in the case of any

other legal entity.  The fact that there are no interested parties in

life insurance companies other than the policyholders does not alter

this fact.

        An individual life insurance policy is a long-term agreement

often running for a period of 30 years or more.

        The amount insured and the premium are fixed on the basis of

an assumed income on invested premiums received.  The surplus that

arises when the actual income is higher, is returned as a bonus on the

policies in accordance with the general mutual principle.

        Depending on the success or otherwise of the insurance

business the aggregate value of the bonus reserve may increase or

decrease.

        Consequently, an insurance policy constitutes a vested right

to the insurance amount contracted in the policy and a right to a

bonus which amounts to a fair share of the surplus, if any.

        As already mentioned, all surplus on life insurance business

is to be returned as a bonus on the policies.  Each individual policy

is entitled to a certain share of the surplus in proportion to its

relative contribution to the creation of the surplus.  This principle

is universal for all life insurance companies.  The manner in which

the allotment of the surplus is effected may nevertheless vary

slightly from one company to another, depending on which way the

individual life insurance company allocates receipts and expenditure

on the policies.  In all cases, the principle of equitable treatment

of policies must be adhered to.  Details on the allotment principles

can be found in each company's general rules.  The actual allocation

of the bonus is not formally effected until the amount insured for

becomes payable.

        It is common for life insurance companies to describe the

importance of the bonus to the future value of insurance policies by

preparing what are referred to as "bonus illustrations".  Such

illustrations often accompany the general information given to

potential buyers of life insurance policies.  The bonus illustrations

do not represent any guarantee of a future bonus to be received on the

policy in question, the intention being simply to show how various

levels of bonus interest are influenced by the factual return on

invested premiums.  It is, nevertheless, the experience that the bonus

illustrations are understood by policyholders as a prognosis of future

bonus, which makes it necessary to prepare all such illustrations on a

very conservative basis and to make a number of reservations.

The particulars of the one-off property tax

        The essential stipulations of the legislation on the property

tax may be summarised as follows.

        The legislation on the property tax was passed by the Swedish

Parliament on 16 December 1986 and published the same day as

No. 1986:1225 of the Swedish Law Gazette.  The Act entered into force

on 23 December 1986.

        The one-off property tax was calculated as 7% of the taxable

assets of the below mentioned companies.  For pension insurance the

taxable assets equalled the aggregate assets of the contributor whereas

the taxable assets for the purpose of endowment insurance were 72% of

the aggregate assets referable to this type of insurances.  No tax

should be paid on that part of a company's assets which were referable

to sickness or accident insurances.  The basic principle was that the

assets were assessed, with certain exceptions, at their book value.

        The one-off property tax was to be paid to the State by

Swedish life insurance companies, certain friendly societies and

pension funds.  The tax liability was imposed on the subjects

concerned which had started business activities before the end of

1984.  No others were subjected to the property tax.  The tax was based

on the entities' aggregate assets in excess of 10 million Swedish

crowns by 31 December 1986.  As a result the levy concerned

approximately 200 companies, societies and funds directly, including

the first and second applicant.  The method of distributing the tax

burden chosen by the first and second applicants, as well as by other

insurance companies affected by the Act, was, in the absence of any

criteria provided for by law, to reduce the bonus payments which would

otherwise have been credited the policyholders for the years 1987 and

1988.        Those entities which were liable to the tax had to file a

special tax return relating to the levy no later than 1 June 1987.  At

the same time one half of the amount to be paid had to be remitted.

One half of the remainder of the amount had to be paid no later than

31 August 1987 and the remaining part on 30 November 1987.

        The property tax was not deductible for the entities concerned

when calculating their income tax to the State.  The one-off tax

totalled approximatelly 16 billion Swedish crowns, and the first and

second applicants paid 916,091,000 and 356,000 Swedish crowns

respectively.

        When the Government presented the new legislation to

Parliament the responsible minister stated inter alia the following:

"Since the autumn of 1982, economic policy has aimed at

eliminating the various balance problems in the Swedish

economy.  Among other things, this has involved a strict

budgetary policy aimed at reducing the large budget deficit.

During this period, the margin for improvements, both in the

form of increases in real household income and through public

expenditures, has been extremely narrow.  During these years

large groups of our society have contributed to a pronounced

decrease of the Swedish economy's problems by various types of

sacrifices.  The deficits on the national budget and in the

balance of current payments have thus been reduced or

eliminated.  This has proved possible parallel to a reduction

in unemployment.

The policy pursued - in combination with international

development - has thus made a radical reduction in the rate of

inflation possible.  A necessary condition for continued low

inflation, which is essential for any favourable economic

development in real terms, is that the deficit on the national

budget be further limited in coming years.

It has also proved possible to reduce the level of interest

rates, in that the balance problems in the Swedish economy

have been softened.  However, the fall in interest rates has

not been as rapid as the decrease in the rate of inflation.

While inflation has fallen from 10% in 1982 to around 3% this

year, nominal interest rates have decreased over the same

period from 13% to 9%.  It is not surprising therefore that

the rates of real interest have risen sharply.  Experience shows

that changes in the inflation rate - upwards or downwards -

are only reflected in the nominal rate after a considerable

period of time.  On the other hand, the level of real interest

is almost unique.  Real interest has not been anywhere near

today's level in modern times.

It is impossible to foresee how long the level of real

interest will remain high.  It may be noted, however, that

institutions with a high proportion of their wealth invested

in assets at a tied rate will be in a position to enjoy a

continued high yield for several years after any decision in

the general level of interest rates.  Given continued low

inflation, such investors can even now reckon, with a high

degree of certainty, on a very good real yield, at least for

the remainder of the 1980s, even if the interest on new

investments were to fall.

Through the rise in real interest rates, the yield on

insurance saving has gone up markedly.  One may note, among

other things, a trend increase in the so-called 'refund

rates'.  These show what a yield individual pension and

endowment insurances give for individual years.  In real

terms, the refund rates have thus risen from around 1% in 1981

to approximately 11% this year.  Refund rates can be expected

to remain at this level for a further few years.  Another

factor contributing to the rise in refund rates has been the

rapidly rising rates noted for listed shares, an increase in

value which is the result of the high level of profit in

business and industry.

The increased attractiveness of insurance saving has led to a

strong increase in the demand for policies.  During the period

1980-85, the number of newly subscribed P-insurances rose by

no less than 23% per year, while the number of E-insurances

rose by 16% per year.

At the same time as insurance saving has expanded strongly so

far during the 1980s, total savings by households have

continued to remain low, or actually to fall.  There is thus

reason to believe that the increase in insurance saving has to

a large extent replaced other savings by households.  It also

seems probable that part of this saving, particularly in the

case of E-insurance, has been achieved with borrowed money.

The rapid real growth in the insurance companies' refund rates

- i.e. the yield on insurance saving - is in contrast with the

restricted development of real wages in recent years.  The

high yield entails, in the case of individual insurance

saving, increased benefits.  There is a direct link between

the yield in an insurance company and the scale of, for

example, the pension paid on the grounds of a pension

insurance policy.

In the case of collective insurance saving, the scale of

pensions and other insured benefits is dependent only in part

on the yield on insurance capital.  These benefits are set out

in collective agreements.  If the yield on capital is very

high, as is the case at present, the effect is to render the

costs to the employer lower than otherwise.  It is thus the

employers who, primarily, benefit from the high yield.  That

this is the case is confirmed by the fact that the level of

premiums for service pension insurance has fallen during the

past two years.

General considerations

Life insurance saving enjoys a favoured position in the

context of taxation.  Saving in a pension insurance

(P-insurance) takes place with untaxed money.  The yield on

its capital is not subject to taxation within the insurance

sector.  Only when pension sums are actually paid does a tax

obligation arise.  In the case of endowment policies

(E-insurance), the arrangement if different.  Saving is

effected with taxed money.  The yield is subject to a low rate

of taxation within the insurance company.  The sums that fall

due are exempt from income tax.  The life insurance capital is

entirely exempt from wealth tax and is favourably treated, by

comparison with other assets, in inheritance taxation.  Also,

it should be noted that the costs to an employer of service

pensions and other 'security' insurances for the employees are

not included in the basis for the employers' social charges.

It will be clear from what I have now said that the entire

life insurance sector is consistently afforded a favourable

treatment as regards taxation.  This is the case both

regarding individual insurance savings, and the savings based

on collective agreements between labour and management.  Even

if the rules are differently structured in respect of P- and

E-insurance, both types are favoured, compared with other

types of savings.

It is not without reason, however, that benefits have been

accorded to savings in the form of insurance.  The long-term

character ascribable to most insurance savings is generally

desirable.  Savings in the form of insurance mean that the

saver often ties up funds over long periods of time.  Even if

the financial security ensured in sickness and old age has

been radically improved by the development of the national

insurance, there is reason also to provide conditions

favouring a complementary financial protection, whether this

is based on collective agreements, or created by individual

insurance solutions.

The benefits accorded, in taxation, to insurance savings are

for the reasons I have just quoted, among others, essentially

well considered during periods when the growth of insurance

capital is normal.  As I have indicated, however, in the

preceding section, we are currently experiencing a growth of

wealth in the insurance sector that one is bound to

characterise as unique.  The yield on insurance capital now

lies at a level in excess of 10%.  No such situation has

prevailed at all in modern times.  I would observe, in this

context, that fluctuations in the yield are per se a regular

feature in insurance company operations.  Periods when the

real yield is low, or actually negative, alternate with

periods when the yield is at a higher level.  What we are now

experiencing, however, is a growth in whealth far beyond what

can be contained by such normal fluctuations.

.....................

In the light of what I have just said, I have reached the

conclusion that the disadvantages connected with a tax on real

interest are so considerable as to prevent me from

recommending the introduction of such a tax.  My position

entails that a solution to the problems of income distribution

consequent upon the growth of wealth in the insurance sector

must be sought along different lines.  As already stated, it is

my opinion that the general order of things prevailing as

regards the taxation of insurance savings affords an

acceptable result both when profitability is good, and when it

is bad.  In the situation currently prevailing, however, with

a growth of wealth that is unique in modern times, the

favoured position of insurance savings from the standpoint of

taxation entails that such savings are enjoying benefits on a

scale that must be called into question.  In my opinion,

special measures are thus called for.

When considering the thrust of such measures, one should in my

opinion take into account precisely the circumstance that the

present level of yield will not persist.  In a few years' time,

we can foresee a return to a more normal level of

profitability.  What has just been said leads also to the

conclusion that no other new, permanent forms of taxation

should be introduced.  On the contrary, it would be sufficient

to exact, now, a (one-off) wealth tax from the insurance

sector.  Such a tax would not entail drawbacks of the kind

associated with a tax on real interest.  An occasional tax can

be simply structured.  It will not create uncertainty

regarding the future as to the scale of the tax to be exacted

on insurance savings.  Also, its budgetary effects can be

entirely estimated.

By way of summary, I would make the following judgment.  The

growth of wealth noted within the life insurance sector is at

present at such a level that the favourable tax rules applying

produce results that are unreasonable from the point of view

of distribution-of-income policy.  The present situation is in

the historical perspective almost unique, and cannot be

expected to persist over any long period of time.  To alter

the fundamental tax provisions or introduce an entirely new,

permanent system of taxation to meet the present situation can

produce undesirable long-term effects.  By a (one-off) wealth

tax, one avoids such effects, at the same time as the sector

which is being favoured with particular force by successful

efforts to combat inflation is required to contribute to a

clean-up of the state's finances.  My conclusion is therefore

that the rules of the taxation of life insurance should be

retained, in their essentials, but that an occasional tax

should be exacted.  I would also add, at this point, that this

tax will create the possibility for improvements for those

pensioners who are worst off."

The Swedish Law Council (Lagrådet)

        The proposal the Swedish Government presented to Parliament

was under the Constitution submitted for scrutiny from a legal point

of view by an institution called the Law Council.  This Council is

composed of three members from the country's supreme legal

institutions, the Supreme Court (Högsta Domstolen) and the Supreme

Administrative Court (Regeringsrätten).  In the present case, two

Supreme Court judges and a Supreme Administrative Court judge

scrutinised the bill and gave their opinion on 31 October 1986.

        Concerning the compatibility of the Government bill with the

Swedish Constitution and the European Convention on Human Rights, the

Law Council made the following statement:

"The Council has in particular studied the bill from its

constitutional aspects.  In this respect, the Council has

started from the statement in the remittted proposal that

the bill, if a decision is made by Parliament before its

Christmas recess, will not be in conflict with the

prohibition against retroactive tax legislation contained

in Chapter 2 Section 10 of the Instrument of Government,

nor with any Swedish commitments under international

treaties.  By the latter are envisaged, presumably, the

European Convention of 4 November 1950 on the Protection

of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms together with the

supplementary protocol of 20 March 1952 relating to the

protection of, among other things, property rights.  The

Council has also considered the compatibility of the bill

with these documents, which for the sake of simplicity are

referred to below as the European Convention.

...................

A circumstance considered inter alia in many statements by the

bodies to whom the bill was circulated is that it is intended

to tax insurance companies etc. for a wealth that they only

manage in accordance with agreements with the policyholders.

This view is developed, among others, by the Court of Appeal

for Western Sweden (hovrätten för västra Sverige), which found

the construction objectionable on legal grounds and recommended

that the liability to tax rest with the owner of the wealth

asset.  Applying a strict judgment by the terms of the Instrument

of Government, the Law Council finds, to begin with, that there

is no obstacle to exacting tax on the actual wealth assets in

question.  Whether a tax is exacted in one way or another, from

the insurance institutions or the policyholders, is a question

to which inter alia practical administrative considerations can

obviously be applied.  The Council cannot find any legal obstacle

to the construction which has been chosen.  It is of major

importance, however, that the tax should ultimately burden the

individuals involved in accordance with fair and objective

principles.  Satisfactory guarantees of this should be available

within the framework of the control system that would be in

operation under the Act, and in view of the tax subjects in

question.

On the other hand, the wealth tax's character of a once-for-all

tax presents a major problem.  It should be noted per se that

alterations to taxes, and above all, charges that limit their

period of application in various ways have been made on numerous

occasions.  In this context, an example close to hand can be

recalled in the Act (1983:968) concerning an Occasional Increase

in the State Wealth Tax, which applied to the assessment of 1984

and was introduced as one among many aspects of a larger proposal

on economic policy.  The background, according to the Government's

bill (1983/84:40 p. 32) was that the wealth values of certain

assets had risen dramatically.  It was not considered acceptable

that this increase in value should benefit only a limited group

of citizens.  The objections raised by those entering reservations

in the Standing Committee on the Constitution lack relevance

in the present context.

In the present case, however, it is a question not of any

temporary change in a previously payable tax, but of the

introduction of an entirely new wealth tax of a once-for-all

character.  This has given rise to certain special constitutional

questions, which have not previously been brought forward.

The Law Council recalls that the idea of a once-for-all tax on

wealth was raised during the Second World War.  A memorandum

regarding the conditions for and consequences of such a tax

was compiled by Professor Erik Lindahl (SOU 1942:52).  The

question was raised several times in Parliament, most

recently by the Standing Committee of Ways and Means in 1945

(No. 55), shortly after the end of the war in Europe.  The

majority of the Standing Committee then recommended an enquiry

into the forms in which private wealth should contribute to

the covering of the expenditures arising during the period of

the emergency.  The minority did not quote any constitutional

grounds against the proposal.  The general opinion appears to

have been that extraordinary measures were permitted in

conditions of crisis.  The national defence tax, for example,

had been introduced with retroactive effects.  The same came

to apply - but here with political differences of opinion - to

the excess profit tax exacted on income from business and

agricultural operations during 1951, against the background of

the Korean War.  This latter tax became in fact an example of

a once-for-all tax.

A once-for-all tax on wealth is obviously of a more sensitive

nature than a once-for-all tax on income.  It is one thing to

exact a tax that is in principle of the customary general

nature - as was the case during the war - another to abandon

this general nature, and instead limit, with a greater or

lesser degree of narrowness, the circle of tax-liable

entities.  In the present case, the number of entities liable

to tax is said to be around 2,000, but the majority will

escape taxation owing to the deduction of 10 million Swedish

crowns which it is proposed to allow.  The Council finds that

a basis is lacking on which to calculate the number of

entities liable in practice.  Still less can the Council

arrive at any general picture as to how the deduction will

influence the effects of the tax on different policyholders

and persons entitled to pensions.

In the field of tax legislation it is accepted - obviously -

that a relatively far-reaching differentiation be made between

different taxable entities, and between different kinds of

receipts, property and other sources of tax.  However, the

limit for what can be regarded as acceptable is by no means

unproblematic.

In the case of a wealth tax, special problems arise in view of

the provision contained in Chapter 2 Section 18 of the

Instrument of Government regarding expropriation and similar

procedures.  The Instrument of Government recognises no other

procedures - we are here disregarding penalties for legal

offences, and the like - for the transfer of property from the

individual to the society than those envisaged in this

provision and those effected through taxes etc.  The more

detailed import of the term 'tax' is not apparent from any

provision in the Instrument of Government, nor is it further

treated in the preliminaries to the Instrument.  Nonetheless, it

is still worth recalling that the Instrument of Government

entailed a final break with the earlier constitutional fiction

that in principle all taxes were decided for one year at a

time.  Even if it is clear that Parliament still has the

authority to decide upon a limitation in time, the

circumstance quoted contains a factor that urges a generally

cautious approach to once-for-all taxes.  It must, at least,

be said to lie in the structure and spirit of the Instrument

of Government that the taxing power should not circumvent the

provision laid down in Chapter 2 Section 18 by specially

directed interventions of a once-for-all character against

property.

The discussion concerning disputed proposals for new or

increased taxes often raises the question of limits of the

taxing power, and more specifically the boundary between tax

and confiscation.  The question has also been discussed in the

legal literature both prior to the advent of the Instrument of

Government and thereafter.  As developed (in this literature),

the confiscation argument is frequently used in tax

discussions in a manner unacceptable from the legal point of

view.  What is stated in the literature clearly indicates that

the bill now under consideration cannot be said to entail

an illegal confiscation.

Similar points of view to those presented above are also

relevant when one considers the compatibility of the

proposal with the European Convention (....).  According to

(Article 1 of Protocol No. 1), the right to property shall be

respected.  No one shall be deprived of his property other

than in the public interest and on the conditions indicated in

the law of the country and by the general principles of

international law.  It is also, however, stated that this

shall not impair the right of a State to enforce laws to

secure the payment of taxes and charges.  Only in isolated

cases have questions relating to taxes been criticised under

the provisions of the Convention.  One case related to a

once-for-all tax of 25% on wealth above a certain limit,

decided upon in a Nordic country in critical economic

circumstances.  By a decision of 20 December 1960, the case,

as being "manifestly ill-founded", was not taken up by the

Commission for consideration (No. 511/59, Dec. 20.12.60,

Collection 4 p. 1 at p. 33) A similar decision was made on 2

December 1985 by reason of a complaint against the Swedish

profit sharing tax (No. 11036/84, Dec. 2.12.85, to be

published in D.R.).

It should be observed that a development in the direction of

stronger protection for ownership rights has been reflected in

the findings of the European Court in recent years.  Greater

importance has also been accorded to (Article 14 of the

Convention) which prescribes that enjoyment of the freedoms

and rights set forth in the Convention shall be secured

without discrimination on any ground, such as sex, race,

language, or other status.  In the Council's view, however,

there is no basis for claiming that the bill here in question

is in breach of the European Convention.

The Law Council returns here to the statements in the remitted

proposal, quoted in the introduction to the effect that the

bill is not in breach of any provision in the Instrument of

Government etc.  As will have become apparent from the reasoning

of the Council, these statements in no way exhaust the

constitutional problems.  The provisions of the Instrument of

Government, like its preliminaries, are far from exhaustive,

and are in several areas, including that of the financial

power, couched in markedly brief and general terms.  It is

illustrative, for example, that the import of the concept of

law is discussed in detail in the preliminaries, while the

concept of 'tax' is hardly touched upon.  In this situation,

it becomes of great importance how the content of the

Instrument of Government is implemented through the actions of

the executive powers.

The Council recalls that our constitutional law, prior to the

constitutional reform, was based essentially on constitutional

practice, which on many points had acquired substance only

after prolonged dispute.  It is obvious that the implementation

of the new Instrument of Government by a suitable and workable

practice is a matter of great urgency.  Essentially, it is, of

course, for Parliament and Government to shoulder this

responsibility.  Against this background, it is a serious

shortcoming of the remitted proposal that it fails to provide

either any material basis for judgment or any statements for

guidance.

In scrutinising any proposed legislation that raises the

question of how the Instrument of Government is to be given

substance in legal practice, it is an important task for the

Council to report its view from the perspective this Council

is set to represent.  In the present case, it is thus required

to do this without any support in the remitted proposal.

The Law Council cannot ignore the possibility of this bill

providing the starting-point of a development that could give

rise to very serious doubts, in view of the grounds on which

the Instrument of Government rests.  Reference can be made,

apart from Chapter 2 Section 18, to inter alia the fact

that Chapter 1 Section 2 establishes the economic welfare of

the individual as a fundamental objective of public

activities.  This is the first occasion on which a bill is

submitted for a once-for-all tax on wealth that lacks a

general nature.  Such a tax fits somewhat badly per se into our

constitutional system.  It could also constitute grounds for

various once-for-all property taxes to be exacted from a

narrowly limited circle of taxable entities, and with higher

rates of taxation than that which we are now considering.  It

is true that nothing of this kind is evident from the remitted

proposal.  Nor, however, does it contain any statement expressing

rejection of such a development.

The bill as circulated, would, in the opinion of the Law

Council, create an unfortunate precedent in a sensitive area,

in which the regulation provided by the constitutional laws is

incomplete and unclear, and the formation of practice

therefore acquires special importance.  One should also in

particular note that the country is not in any such critical

situation as is mentioned in, for example, Chapter 2 Section

10 of the Instrument of Government.  Decisions taken in

extraordinary circumstances of that kind have limited, if any,

force as precedents in normal times.  If this bill is enacted,

however, one is acquiring a precedent that cannot be dismissed

on such grounds.

The same argument also leads the Council to adopt a critical

attitute to the manner in which the bill has been prepared and

presented in the remitted proposal.  The further constitutional

aspects have not been taken into account.  It would have been

highly desirable to have a discussion of these, together with a

normal procedure of circulation for comment.  Shortcomings in

the preparation of the bill are evident also in other respects

than the constitutional.  It is admittedly true that it has

been possible, in the treatment of various details, to build

on the report of the Committee on Taxation of Real Interest

and the statements of the bodies circulated, but the

construction in principle of the bill is entirely different,

and the effects of it have not been illustrated in any

satisfactory manner.  The Law Council has, for example, drawn

critical attention to the lack of clarity as to who will

actually be burdened by the tax.

The bill emerges almost as an improvisation, produced when a

bill for a new and permanent tax was rejected.  It is

difficult to avoid the reflection that closer consideration

could have led to essentially the same purpose having been

gained by another construction, which would not have given

rise to the doubts expressed by the Law Council in the

foregoing.

In the light of these deliberations, the Council finds itself

obliged to recommend against implementation of the proposed

legislation remitted to it."

COMPLAINTS

Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 to the Convention

        In the applicants' view the primary issue to be determined

under this Article and which is inherent in the Convention as a whole,

is whether a fair balance has been struck between the public or

general interest and the protection of the proprietary rights and

interests of the applicants.  The purpose and effects of the Act in

question are clearly concerned with the deprivation of property, with

the result that the second sentence of the first paragraph of Article

1 of Protocol No. 1 is applicable.   Moreover, since the present case

involves the payment of taxes, it falls to be considered not only

under the terms of the second sentence of the first paragraph, but

also under the second paragraph of Article 1.

        The applicants recognise, as is made clear by the second

paragraph itself, that the margin of appreciation given to national

authorities under Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 in the field of economic

and fiscal regulation, is necessarily a wide one.  However, it is

well-established in the Commission's case-law that the powers of

taxation are not immune from review under the Convention (cf. for

example No. 8531/79, Dec. 10.3.81, D.R. 23 p. 203).

        It follows that although the Act involves the payment of a

tax, this fact does not exclude the circumstances of the present case

from the effective protection afforded by Article 1 of Protocol No. 1

and the other relevant provisions of the Convention.  The relevant

principles are as follows:

  (i)   Although the margin of appreciation available to the national

        legislature under Article 1 is a wide one, the measure imposed

        must have a legitimate aim, in the sense of not being

        "manifestly without reasonable foundation" (cf. for example,

        Eur.  Court H.R., James and others judgment of 21 February 1986,

        Series A No. 98).

(ii)   Where the measure has a legitimate aim, there must be a

        reasonable relationship of proportionality between the means

        employed and the aim sought to be realised.

(iii)   A fair balance must be struck between the demands of the

        general interest of the community and the requirements of the

        protection of the individual's fundamental rights, and this

        balance will not be struck if the measure results in a person

        or a section of the public having an individual and excessive

        burden (cf.  Eur.  Court H.R., Sporrong and Lönnroth judgment of

        23 September 1982, Series A No. 52).

        For the reasons given below the Act, which is both grossly

unfair in its operation and lacking in any objective and reasonable

justification, falls well short of satisfying these principles, and

exceeds the Swedish State's margin of appreciation.

        Under the second sentence of the first paragraph of Article 1

of Protocol No. 1 a deprivation of possessions must not only be in the

public interest, but must also be "subject to the conditions provided

for by law".  The applicants submit that this principle, which is

inherent in the Convention as a whole, applies to every case in which

the right to property guaranteed by Article 1 falls to be considered.

It is evident from the jurisprudence of the European Court of Human

Rights that State action does not necessarily comply with the

principle of legal certainty, guaranteed by these requirements, merely

by reason of the fact that it is in conformity with domestic law.  The

requirement that a measure must be prescribed by law can thus be seen

to include the requirements that it must satisfy the principle of

legal certainty and not be arbitrary.

        The Act fails to satisfy these requirements for the following

reasons.

        The Act itself is arbitrary, in that its scope and application

are restricted, in a discriminatory manner and without any objective

and reasonable justification, to certain mutual life insurance

companies, friendly societies and pension foundations and hence their

beneficiaries, leaving other entities and individuals unaffected.

        Further, the operation of the Act is arbitrary, in that it

provides no means for the relevant companies to determine the way in

which the burden of the tax should be distributed, and thus fails to

provide the individual policyholder or other beneficiary with any

guarantee that he or she will not be unjustly burdened as compared to

other policyholders or beneficiaries.  It is not expedient for the

insurance companies and other institutions, nor is it their function,

to redress the arbitrary nature of the tax by the manner in which they

transfer the burden upon the policyholders and other beneficiaries.

The institutions are not, for example, required to apply a means test,

nor to have regard to the family and other individual circumstances of

the policyholders and other beneficiaries.  From the point of view,

therefore, of those who are the real taxpayers under the Act, the

operation of the legislation is inherently arbitrary, as well as being

neither adequately accessible nor sufficiently precise.  For these

reasons there has been a breach not only of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1,

but also, as will be shown below, of Article 6 and Article 13 of the

Convention.

        The Act involves the legislative taking by the Swedish

Government of a large part of the savings and pension benefits of

several million men and women (both Swedish and non-Swedish nationals),

which have accumulated in the hands of life insurance companies,

friendly societies and pension foundations.  The levying of the 7%

one-off wealth tax involves a deprivation of the applicants'

proprietary rights and interests.  It is therefore necessary to

consider whether the taking of property provided for by, or as a

consequence of, the Act was in accordance with the principles of

fairness, proportionality, legal certainty and non-discrimination

which are inherent in Article 1 of Protocol No. 1, and in the

Convention as a whole.

        The stated aim of the Swedish Government in introducing the

unprecedented measure was to reduce the national debt by redistributing

wealth from the private sector to the public sector.  Whilst

the applicants accept that the redistribution of wealth from more

favoured to less favoured groups in society is a legitimate aim the

arbitrary and discriminatory taking of wealth from particular sections

of the public, in circumstances in which there is no "fair balance",

constitutes an aim which is "manifestly without reasonable foundation".

The effect of the occasional wealth tax will be to appropriate to the

Swedish State 16-18 billion Swedish crowns, in the context of total

revenues from State income tax amounting to approximately 60 billion

Swedish crowns.  In other words, the Government seek by the levying of

this tax to increase the revenue of the State by about one third of

the revenue normally obtained through State income tax.  Furthermore,

it does so at the expense of the individual policyholders and their

dependants, irrespective of their individual means and particular

circumstances.  In a formal sense the tax is levied under the Act upon

the life insurance companies, friendly societies and pension

foundations.  But in reality the effective burden of this tax is

necessarily borne by individual policyholders and other beneficiaries.

        These policyholders and beneficiaries are ordinary men and

women, the majority of whom could not be said to be particularly

wealthy.  The Act provides no guidance as to how the burden of the tax

should be distributed between those individuals.  The mutual life

insurance companies to which the Act applies have decided to

distribute the burden by reducing, on a pro rata basis, the bonus

payments that would otherwise have been made to policyholders in 1987

and 1988.  There can be no doubt that under this method of

distribution, the appropriation by the State of 7% of the assets of

the institutions in whose hands the savings and pension benefits of

policyholders have been placed, will have had the effect of

diminishing the proprietary rights and interests of many people of

comparatively modest means, who do not "deserve" to be taxed under a

special wealth tax by reason of their individual means or particular

circumstances.  Whatever method is chosen to distribute the burden,

the insurance companies and other relevant institutions cannot avoid

the arbitrary and unfair consequences for the policyholders and their

dependants.  On the other hand, there will necessarily be many people

who will not be affected by the Act, who are much wealthier, and whose

means and circumstances would much more readily justify the imposition

of a wealth tax than in the case of many of those who are affected by

the Act.  A tax which is imposed irrespective of the individual means

and particular circumstances of those who will ultimately bear the

burden of the tax is inherently arbitrary, capricious and

discriminatory in its operation and effect.  In the applicants'

submission, therefore, to increase State revenues by means of such a

tax cannot constitute a legitimate aim in the public or general

interest, within the meaning of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 to the

Convention.

        Further, there is no reasonable relationship of proportionality

between the operation of the Act and the Swedish State's proclaimed

aim of reducing the national debt by redistributing wealth from the

private sector to the public sector.  As a means of attaining this

stated aim, the occasional wealth tax operates as a grossly unfair and

discriminatory measure, which places the burden of redistribution

entirely on the shoulders of one section of the Swedish public, that

is, those who have chosen to save and to provide for the future of

themselves and their dependants by means of pension or endowment

insurance, or by placing funds with friendly societies or pension

foundations, or whose employers have chosen to make such arrangements

on their behalf.  By contrast, those whose future pension benefits are

provided for by a different arrangement, for example, those whose

pension is directly paid to them by their employer, are not affected

by this tax, because they are outside the scope of the Act.  Nor is a

corresponding tax burden placed upon the large group of public

servants who are entitled to a state service pension or a local

government pension.  Their pension benefits are safeguarded against

the effects of inflation, and they do not, therefore, have the same

need to provide for the future by means of private pension insurance.

Furthermore, those who are outside the scope of the Act have not had

to bear any risk that the value of their pension benefits may be

affected by a decline in the value of the shares in which their

pension funds have been invested.

        The operation of the tax is a measure which fails entirely to

strike a fair balance between the demands of the general interest and

the requirements of the protection of the applicants' fundamental

righs.  Even assuming that it is in certain circumstances a legitimate

aim for the Swedish Government to seek, in the general interest, to

reduce the national debt by a redistribution of wealth from the

private sector to the public sector, Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 to

the Convention does not permit this to be done arbitrarily and

unjustly at the expense of the proprietary rights and interests of one

particular section of the public, irrespective of their individual

means or particular circumstances, leaving the rights and interests of

other sections of the public unaffected.  The fair balance requirement

entails that no one section of the public bears a wholly

disproportionate individual and excessive burden, at whose expense

there is unjust enrichment by the State.

        Furthermore, the effect of the Act is also to leave intact, in

an arbitrary and discriminatory manner, the savings and pension

benefits of those who hold pension insurance policies with many

smaller insurance companies whose wealth does not exceed 10 million

Swedish crowns, or which were formed after 1984.  Accordingly, those

wealthy individuals, who have large pension savings in institutions

outside the scope of the Act, remain wholly unaffected by the tax or

any equivalent tax.  By contrast, individuals of modest means, who

have small pension savings in institutions subject to the Act, have

their pension benefits diminished by virtue of the operation of the

Act.

        The Act thus amounts to a taking of property by the Swedish

State which is manifestly not in the public interest or within the

scope of the second paragraph of Article 1.  It is the arbitrary,

capricious and discriminatory nature and effect of the Act, its

failure to draw any distinction based on the individual means and

circumstances of policyholders and other beneficiaries, the absence of

any reasonable proportionality, which take the occasional wealth tax

outside the scope of any proper use of the economic and fiscal

regulatory powers exercisable by the legislature and the executive

in a modern society governed by the rule of law.

        It is further submitted that the imposition of the tax does

not constitute a deprivation "subject to the conditions provided for

by law" in that the effect of the Act is in practice, although not in

theory, retrospective.  Through the imposition of the occasional

wealth tax upon the assets of life insurance companies, friendly

societies and pension foundations, the savings and pension benefits of

individual policyholders and other beneficiaries over many years are

in effect appropriated by the State.  The Act was passed by Parliament

on 16 December 1986 and it entered into force on 23 December 1986.

In practice, individual policyholders and other beneficiaries were

deprived of any real and effective opportunity to regulate their

conduct so as to mitigate the adverse consequences of the Act for

them.

        The applicants further submit that a deprivation of property

by the imposition of a wealth tax must not only be "subject to the

conditions provided for by law", but must also be subject to "the

general principles of international law".

        However, if there is any practical difference in the

circumstances of the present case (which is not admitted) between the

standard of treatment required for nationals and for non-nationals

under Article 1, then it is submitted that the non-Swedish nationals

are plainly entitled to rely upon the general principles of

international law for the protection of their property rights.

        By imposing the tax upon non-Swedish nationals, the Swedish

State has failed to comply with the general principles of international

law.  The tax was arbitrary, discriminatory and grossly unfair, lacking

any reasonable foundation or relationship of reasonable proportionality

with its stated aim.  It thus amounted in reality to a confiscation of

property without the payment of prompt, adequate and effective

compensation by the Swedish State.

Article 14 of the Convention in conjunction with Article 1 of

Protocol No. 1 to the Convention

        By introducing the tax in question applicable only to certain

life insurance companies, friendly societies and pension foundations,

the Act clearly subjected the institutions so affected, as well as

their policyholders and other beneficiaries, to a different kind of

treatment in their enjoyment of the right to property guaranteed by

Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 to the Convention which had no objective

and reasonable justification, and in relation to which there was no

reasonable proportionality between the means employed and the Swedish

Government's stated aim of reducing the national debt.  These points

have already been developed above.

Article 6 para. 1 of the Convention

        The applicants further submit that their right to a fair

judicial process under Article 6 of the Convention has been violated.

        The applicants' right of property is a "civil right" within

the meaning of Article 6 para. 1.  It is submitted that the applicants

had no effective right to a fair hearing in respect of the protection

of the enjoyment of the substance of their right to property, insofar

as this right was affected by the arbitrary and discriminatory

operation and effects of the tax.

        The tax, although formally applicable only to certain companies,

is in reality a tax imposed on individual policyholders and other

beneficiaries, whose proprietary rights and interests are adversely

affected by it.  The Act, however, fails to recognise this fact or its

implications.  It leaves it open to insurance companies, for example,

to reduce the savings of policyholders on a pro rata basis, regardless

of whether a person's policy has in fact benefited from the favourable

returns enjoyed by insurance companies on their investments in the

past few years.  By leaving the method of distribution of the "real"

burden of the tax in the hands of private institutions, the Swedish

Government and legislature have failed entirely to recognise or to

apply the principles according to which the fiscal powers of a State

are ordinarily exercised, namely, that the burden of a tax should be

distributed by taking into account the individual means and particular

circumstances of those who must bear the burden.

        By failing to provide any criteria for the distribution of the

tax as between those who in reality are the taxpayers, the Act has

created a legal vacuum in relation to the fair determination by

judicial process of the applicants' right to property.  The

Convention has not been incorporated into Swedish law, and there are

no equivalent rules or principles of Swedish law upon which a Swedish

court or tribunal, faced with the task of determining the extent of an

individual's proprietary rights and interests in relation to the tax,

could make a fair and just decision.

        In these circumstances, the applicants submit that there is a

systematic failure on the part of Sweden effectively to secure the

right to property to everyone within the jurisdiction of this State,

without unfair discrimination, and to ensure that everyone is

afforded, in the determination of his civil rights and obligations, a

fair and public hearing, as required by Article 6 para. 1 of the

Convention.

Article 13 of the Convention

        The applicants do not seek to argue that Article 13 guarantees

a remedy which allows the Act as such to be challenged before a

national authority as being contrary to the Convention.  However, they

complain that, as a result of Sweden's failure to incorporate the

rights and obligations of the Convention into domestic law, or

otherwise adequately to secure the enjoyment of the applicants' rights

under the Convention in domestic law, the applicants had no effective

and sufficient remedies before any national authority, in respect of

violations of their right to property guaranteed by the Convention,

insofar as such violations are the result of the application of the

Act to life insurance companies and other private institutions and by

such institutions to the policyholders.

Article 18 of the Convention

        The applicants submit that the only restrictions permitted in

relation to the right to property guaranteed by Article 1 of Protocol

No. 1 are those which are in the public general interest.  It follows

that any interference with the right to property which is not in the

public or general interest, constitutes a violation of Article 18, as

well as of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1.  The Act in question thus

constitutes a violation of Article 18 of the Convention, as its

purpose and application are not in accordance with the public

interest, contrary to Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 read on its own, and

read in conjunction with Article 14 of the Convention.  The reasons

for this have been set out above.

THE LAW

1.      The applicants have complained that the introduction in 1986

of the legislation in Sweden concerning the once and for all property

tax involves a breach of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) to the

Convention which reads:

"Every natural or legal person is entitled to the peaceful

enjoyment of his possessions.  No one shall be deprived of his

possessions except in the public interest and subject to the

conditions provided for by law and by the general principles

of international law.

The preceding provisions shall not, however, in any way impair

the right of a State to enforce such laws as it deems

necessary to control the use of property in accordance with

the general interest or to secure the payment of taxes or

other contributions or penalties."

        It is clear from Article 25 para. 1 (Art. 25-1) of the

Convention that the Commission can receive an application from a

person, non-governmental organisation or group of individuals only if

such person, non-governmental organisation or group of individuals can

claim to be a victim of a violation by one of the High Contracting

Parties of the rights set forth in the Convention.  Moreover, the

Commission is competent to examine the compatibility of domestic

legislation with the Convention only with respect to its application

in a concrete case, while it is not competent to examine in abstracto

its compatibility with the Convention (cf. for example No. 11045/84,

Dec. 8.3.85, D.R. 42 p. 247).

        Accordingly, the Commission will only examine the applicants'

complaints insofar as the legislation in question affects the

applicants themselves.

        The applicants have alleged that the one-off tax upon certain

companies is an interference with property rights which, therefore,

can only be accepted insofar as the interference is legally justified

under the exceptions in the second sentence of the first paragraph or

the second paragraph of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) to the

Convention.

        The Commission finds that the first and second applicants may

claim to be victims of an alleged violation of Article 1 of Protocol

No. 1 to the Convention (P1-1).  Their assets as a whole enjoy the

protection of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) and the obligation to

pay the levy is thus an interference with their right to peaceful

enjoyment of their possessions.

        The third applicant is a group of approximately 15,000 persons

who are policyholders in the first and second applicant companies.  The

question arises whether these persons can be considered victims within

the meaning of Article 25 (Art. 25) of the Convention.

        The applicants have argued that in the end it is the third

applicant who will have to bear the burden of the one-off tax as the

insurance companies just administer the money and reduce the profits

to the disadvantage of the third applicant in order to cover the

losses suffered from the one-off tax.  In such circumstances the third

applicant - the group of individual insurance policyholders - is

directly affected by the new legislation.

        The European Court of Human Rights has held that the term

"victim" in Article 25 (Art. 25) of the Convention denotes the person

directly affected by the act or omission which is at issue (cf.  Eur.

Court H.R., Eckle judgment of 15 July 1982, Series A No. 51, p. 30,

para. 66).  Neither the Court nor the Commission has previously

considered the special relationship which exists between a company and

a group of individuals such as the present one, but the Commission has

held in two cases that a shareholder was entitled to claim to be a

victim of measures directed against a company (No. 1706/62, Dec.

4.10.66, Collection 21 p. 26 and No. 7598/76 Kaplan v.  United

Kingdom, Comm. Report 17.7.80, D.R. 21 p. 5 (p. 23)).

        However, the Commission recalls that in both cases the

individual concerned held a substantial majority shareholding in the

company.  In effect both applicants were carrying out their own

business through the medium of the company and both applicants had a

direct personal interest in the subject-matter of the complaint.  Thus

in Application No. 1706/62 the applicant alleged that the actions of

which he complained were part of a general scheme aimed against him

personally.  The Kaplan case concerned restrictions imposed on the

company on the basis of the applicant's alleged personal unfitness to

act as a controller.

        In the case of Yarrow and others (No. 9266/81, Dec. 28.1.83,

D.R. 30 p. 155 (p. 185)) the Commission held that the applicants, who

did not hold a majority or controlling interest in the company in

question, were not directly and personally affected by the measure

taken (the nationalisation of the company) even though this measure

undoubtedly reduced the value of their shareholdings and they could

not therefore claim to be victims within the meaning of Article 25

(Art. 25) of the Convention.

        The circumstances of the present case are, in the Commission's

view, comparable to the latter decision.  Through the insurance

policies the applicant group of individuals has a right to an amount

contracted in the individual policies and a right to a bonus which

amounts to a fair share of the surplus on the life insurance business,

if any.  This bonus is accordingly not a fixed sum, but depends on the

success of the insurance company.

        Furthermore, the Commission recalls that the policyholders do

not have any legal claim to direct ownership of the first and second

applicant companies' assets as such.  All property in which the

companies invest their funds is the companies' own property as in the

case of any other legal entity.  Also the individuals in question are

not required to pay any tax but their "burden" lies in the fact that

the applicant companies for the years 1987 and 1988 reduce the bonus

which would otherwise have been allotted to insurance policy claims,

once they become payable.  Whether the insurance companies under their

contractual obligations are entitled to act in such a way vis-à-vis

their policyholders is not a matter which the Commission is called

upon to determine, but in the circumstances indicated above the

Commission finds that the legislation in question does not affect the

applicant group of individuals directly and personally to such an

extent that it may claim to be a victim under Article 25 (Art. 25) of

the Convention in regard to the first complaint to be considered by

the Commission.  It follows that this part of the application, so far

as brought by the third applicant, is manifestly ill-founded and must

therefore be considered inadmissible under Article 27 para. 2 (Art.

27-2) of the Convention.

        It thus remains to examine whether the interference with the

first and second applicants' rights was justified.

        The first and second applicants (hereafter the applicants)

submit in regard to this particular complaint that the purpose and

effects of the Act in question are clearly concerned with the

deprivation of property, with the result that the second sentence of

the first paragraph of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) is applicable.

Moreover they maintain that, since the present case involves the

payment of taxes, it also falls to be considered under the second

paragraph of Article 1 (P1-1).

        The Commission is of the opinion that any legislation which

introduces some sort of fiscal obligation will as such deprive the

involved of a possession, namely the amount of money which must be

paid.  However, the second sentence of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1

(P1-1) to the Convention expressly secures to the States, parties to

the Convention, the right to enforce such laws as they deem necessary

to secure the payment of taxes or other contributions.  Accordingly,

the Commission will first consider whether the interference with the

applicants' right under Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) is

justified by the second paragraph before considering, if necessary,

whether the requirements set out in the second sentence of the first

paragraph are fulfilled.

        The Commission recalls that the applicants were obliged to

pay, with certain exceptions, a sum equivalent to 7% of their assets

in excess of 10 million Swedish crowns by 31 December 1986.  The

applicant companies thus paid 916,091,000 and 356,000 Swedish crowns

respectively.  Accordingly, the tax took the form of a monetary

contribution on capital assets, which nevertheless would not differ

from a monetary contribution applied to any other asset, for example a

piece of land.

        Having regard to this and the maximum percentage of the levy

as well as the general purpose of the law, which will be further

recalled below, the effects on the applicants were not such as could

deprive the legislation of the character of a tax within the meaning

of the second paragraph of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) (cf.

mutatis mutandis No. 511/59, Gudmundsson v.  Iceland, Dec. 20.12.60,

Collection 4 p. 1 at p. 33).  Nevertheless this does not bring the

issue wholly outside the Commission's control since the correct

application of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) is subject to

supervision by the Convention organs.

        Under this supervision the Commission finds that, though it is

certain that no general prohibition of taxes payable exclusively out

of the tax-payer's capital can be derived from Article 1 (P1-1), a

financial liability arising out of the raising of taxes or

contributions may adversely affect the guarantee secured under this

provision if it places an excessive burden on the person or entity

concerned or fundamentally interferes with his or its financial

position.  However, it is in the first place for the national

authorities to decide what kind of taxes or contributions are to be

collected.  Furthermore the decisions in this area will commonly

involve the appreciation of political, economic and social questions

which the Convention leaves within the competence of the Contracting

States.  The power of appreciation of the Contracting States is

therefore a wide one (cf. No. 11036/84, Dec. 2.12.85, to be published

in D.R.).

        Considering the case in this light the Commission notes the

applicants' contention that, whilst the redistribution of wealth from

more favoured to less favoured groups in society is a legitimate aim,

the arbitrary and discriminatory taking of wealth from particular

sections of the public, in circumstances where there is no "fair

balance", constitutes an aim which is "manifestly without reasonable

foundation".  They contend that the respondent State seeks by the

levying of the tax to increase its revenues by approximately one third

of the revenue normally obtained through income tax.  Furthermore,

there is no reasonable proportionality between the operation of the

act and the State's stated aim of reducing the national debt and thus

it amounts to a taking of property which is manifestly not in the

public interest or within the scope of the second paragraph of Article 1

of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1).

        The Commission also recalls that the main reason for

introducing the one-off tax were considerations concerning a

continuing low inflation, essential in the Government's view for any

favourable economic development, combined with the necessity of a

further limitation of the national budget deficit.  It is undoubtedly

within the sovereign power of a State to enact legislation of this

nature and the Commission finds that this is clearly a measure

introduced with a public purpose and considered by the State to be in

the general interest.  This aim was pursued by levying the one-off tax

on inter alia the applicants amounting to 7% of their assets exceeding

10 million Swedish crowns due, in particular, to the fact that the

situation in the entire life insurance sector was unique at the time

and because of the favourable treatment afforded to this sector as

regards taxation in general, a treatment which is still maintained.  In

such circumstances the Commission cannot find that the one-off tax

affected the applicants' rights of ownership of its assets, be it

monetary or other assets, or interfered with their financial situation

to such an extent that this could be considered disproportionate or an

abuse of the State's right under Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) to

levy taxes.

        It follows that this part of the application is manifestly

ill-founded within the meaning of Article 27 para. 2 (Art. 27-2) of the

Convention.

2.      All three applicants have also complained that by the

introduction of the one-off tax, applicable only to certain insurance

companies, friendly societies and pension foundations, the

institutions affected thereby, as well as their policyholders and

other beneficiaries, were subjected to a specific and unique kind of

treatment in their enjoyment of the right to property guaranteed by

Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) to the Convention which had no

objective and reasonable justification and is thus in violation of

this provision in conjunction with Article 14 (Art. 14) of the

Convention which reads:

"The enjoyment of the rights and freedoms set forth in

this Convention shall be secured without discrimination

on any ground such as sex, race, colour, language,

religion, political or other opinion, national or social

origin, association with a national minority, property,

birth or other status."

        The Commission recalls that Article 14 (Art. 14) has no

independent existence but plays a role only in order to safeguard

persons placed in similar situations from any discrimination in the

enjoyment of the rights and freedoms set forth in the Convention and

its Protocols. Furthermore, as indicated above, the Commission will

only examine the applicants' complaints insofar as the issues raised

affect them directly and personally.

        Regarding the latter point the Commission has found above that

the applicant group of individuals cannot be considered to be affected

directly and personally to the extent that it could claim to be a

victim under Article 25 (Art. 25) of the Convention.  For this reason the

Commission cannot find any issue under Article 14 (Art. 14) and it

follows that this part of the application, insofar as it concerns the

applicant group of individuals, is manifestly ill-founded within the

meaning of Article 27 para. 2 (Art. 27-2) of the Convention.

        Regarding the two applicant companies the Commission has found

above that the taxation interfered with their rights secured to them

under Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) to the Convention but that this

interference was justified in view of the States' right to impose

taxes under the second paragraph of this provision.  However, as

taxation falls within the general scope of Article 1 (P1-1) , it

follows that the prohibition against discrimination in Article 14

(Art. 14) of the Convention is applicable to taxation as such (cf.

No. 8531/79, Dec. 10.3.81, D.R. 23 p. 203 and No. 11089/84, Dec.

11.11.86, to be published in D.R.).

        The Commission, however, also recalls that, in the Belgian

linguistic case (Eur.  Court H.R., judgment of 9 February 1967,

Series A No. 5), the Court stated that it is not every distinction

which amounts to discrimination but that it would arise if the

distinction in question had no objective and reasonable justification.

In particular the Commission considers that it is not sufficient for

the applicants to complain merely that they, rather than others, have

been taxed, but that they must show that the tax in question operates

to distinguish between similar taxpayers on discriminatory grounds.

        Furthermore, as indicated above, the Commission is of the

opinion that in the field of taxation it is for the national

authorities to make the initial assessment of the aims and the means

by which they are pursued.  Accordingly, a margin of appreciation is

left to them and it must be wider in this area than it is in many

others.  The Commission recalls in this respect that systems of

taxation inevitably differentiate between different groups of tax

payers and that the implementation of any taxation system creates

marginal situations.  Also, attitudes as to the social and economic

goals to be pursued by the State in its revenue policy may vary

considerably from place to place and time to time.  A government may

often have to strike a balance between the need to raise revenue and

other objectives in its taxation policies.  The national authorities

are obviously in a better position than the Commission to assess those

needs and requirements.

        In the present case the Commission recalls that the one-off

tax was imposed only on insurance companies, friendly societies and

pension foundations and among them only on those entities which by

31 December 1986 had assets in excess of 10 million Swedish crowns due

to a right for all entities involved to deduct such an amount.  The

Commission also recalls that the reasons for imposing the levy on the

applicants were their unique financial situation at the time combined

with the enjoyment of a favoured position in the context of taxation

in general.

        In the light of this and the above general considerations the

Commission finds that the taxation in question can be said to fall

within the margin of appreciation accorded to the national

authorities; that the difference in treatment, as claimed by the

applicants in the present case, had an objective and reasonable

justification in the aim pursued by the Government; and that the test

of proportionality is satisfied.  It follows that this part of the

application is manifestly ill-founded within the meaning of Article 27

para. 2 (Art. 27-2) of the Convention.

3.      The applicants, invoking Article 6 and 13 (Art. 6, 13) of the

Convention, have furthermore complained that Swedish law provides no

effective remedy before Swedish courts or other authorities with

regard to the questions arising in the present case; under Article 13

(Art. 13) in particular since the Swedish Government have not

incorporated the Convention into domestic law.

        With regard to Article 6 (Art. 6) of the Convention the

Commission has stated above that the levy introduced in Sweden was to

be considered a tax.  The Commission also considered this system to be

covered by the Contracting States' power of taxation expressly

recognised by the Convention.

        The Commission has constantly held that Article 6 (Art. 6) is

not applicable to proceedings regarding taxation (cf.  No. 2552/65,

Dec. 15.12.67, Collection 26 p. 1, No. 2717/66, Dec. 6.2.69, Yearbook

13 p. 176, No. 8903/80, Dec. 8.7.80, D.R. 21 p. 246 and No. 9908/82,

Dec. 4.5.83, D.R. 32 p. 266).  It follows that this part of the

application is incompatible ratione materiae with Article 6 (Art. 6)

of the Convention within the meaning of Article 27 para. 2 (Art.

27-2).

        With regard to Article 13 (Art. 13) of the Convention the

Commission recalls that neither this provision nor the Convention in

general prescribes any particular manner by which the Contracting

States should ensure within their internal law the effective

implementation of the provisions of the Convention (cf.  Eur.  Court

H.R., Swedish Engine Drivers' Union judgment of 6 February 1976,

Series A No. 20, p. 18 para. 50).  Furthermore the Court has stated

that

"by substituting the words 'shall secure' for the words

'undertake to secure' in the text of Article 1 (P1-1), the

drafters of the Convention also intended to make it clear that

the rights and freedoms set out in Section I would be directly

secured to anyone within the jurisdiction of the Contracting

States.  That intention finds a particularly faithful

reflection in those instances where the Convention has been

incorporated into domestic law" (Eur.  Comm.  H.R., Ireland

v. the United Kingdom judgment of 18 January 1978, Series A

No. 25, p. 91 para. 239).

        It follows that Sweden is not obliged to transform the text

of the Convention into Swedish law.

        As to the complaint under Article 13 (Art. 13) the Commission

also recalls that in its judgment in the case of Klass and others the

Court stated that "Article 13 (Art. 13) must be interpreted as guaranteeing an

'effective remedy before a national authority' to everyone who claims

that his rights and freedoms under the Convention have been violated"

(Eur.  Court H.R., Klass and others judgment of 6 September 1978,

Series A No. 28, p. 29, para. 64).

        The Commission has stated in its Report in the case of Sporrong

and Lönnroth against Sweden that it is "obvious that it (Article 13)

(Art. 13) cannot be considered to give an unqualified right to a remedy to

anyone in respect of any complaint as soon as he chooses to invoke the

Convention".  According to the Commission it is necessary "to take

account of the nature of the acts complained of" (Comm.  Report

8.10.80, para. 155).

        In the case of Young, James and Webster against the United

Kingdom the Commission stated that "it cannot be deduced from

Article 13 (Art. 13) that there must be a remedy against legislation

as such which is considered not to be in conformity with the

Convention.  Such a remedy would in effect amount to some sort of

judicial review of legislation because any other review - generally

sufficient for Article 13 (Art. 13) which requires only a remedy

before a national authority - could hardly be effective concerning

legislation" (Comm.  Report 14.12.79, para. 177).

        Without considering it necessary to examine whether all three

applicants in the light of its above conclusions may rely on

Article 13 (Art. 13) of the Convention in the present case, the

Commission is of the opinion that their complaints in substance

concern legislation. Thus, in applying the case-law mentioned above

the Commission finds no appearance of a breach of Article 13 (Art. 13)

as this Article does not relate to legislation and does not guarantee

a remedy by which legislation could be controlled as to its conformity

with the Convention.

        It follows that this part of the application is manifestly

ill-founded within the meaning of Article 27 para. 2 (Art. 27-2) of the

Convention.

4.      The applicants have finally complained that their rights under

Article 18 (Art. 18) of the Convention have been violated.  This

provision reads as follows:

"The restrictions permitted under this Convention to

the said rights and freedoms shall not be applied for any

purpose other than those for which they have been

prescribed."

        The applicants maintain that the above Article has been

violated as the purpose of the tax legislation in question were not in

the public interest as required by Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1)

to the Convention.

        The Commission has already found that the adoption and

application of the new legislation were compatible with Article 1 of

Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) and that the interference on such a basis could be

considered justified as being "to secure the payment of taxes or other

contributions" within the meaning of that provision.  For similar

reasons the Commission does not consider that the enactment and

application of the 1986 Act aimed at the destruction or the excessive

limitation of the applicants' rights under the Convention.

        The Commission accordingly finds no breach of Article 18 (Art.

18) in conjunction with Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) and it

follows that this part of the application is also manifestly

ill-founded within the meaning of Article 27 para. 2 of the

Convention.

        For these reasons, the Commission

        DECLARES THE APPLICATION INADMISSIBLE.

Secretary to the Commission               President of the Commission

      (H. C. KRUGER)                            (C. A. NØRGAARD)

© European Union, https://eur-lex.europa.eu, 1998 - 2024
Active Products: EUCJ + ECHR Data Package + Citation Analytics • Documents in DB: 398107 • Paragraphs parsed: 43931842 • Citations processed 3409255