R. v. SWEDEN
Doc ref: 16239/90 • ECHR ID: 001-941
Document date: July 1, 1991
- 0 Inbound citations:
- •
- 0 Cited paragraphs:
- •
- 0 Outbound citations:
AS TO THE ADMISSIBILITY OF
Application No. 16239/90
by R.
against Sweden
The European Commission of Human Rights sitting in private
on 1 July 1991, the following members being present:
MM. C.A. NØRGAARD, President
J.A. FROWEIN
S. TRECHSEL
E. BUSUTTIL
G. JÖRUNDSSON
A.S. GÖZÜBÜYÜK
A. WEITZEL
J.C. SOYER
H.G. SCHERMERS
H. DANELIUS
Mrs. G.H. THUNE
Sir Basil HALL
MM. F. MARTINEZ
C.L. ROZAKIS
Mrs. J. LIDDY
MM. L. LOUCAIDES
J.-C. GEUS
M.P. PELLONPÄÄ
B. MARXER
Mr. H.C. KRÜGER, Secretary to the Commission
Having regard to Article 25 of the Convention for the
Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms;
Having regard to the application introduced on 20 November 1989
by R. against Sweden and registered on 1 March 1990 under
file No. 16239/90;
Having regard to the report provided for in Rule 47 of the
Rules of Procedure of the Commission;
Having deliberated;
Decides as follows:
FACTS
The facts as submitted by the applicant may be summarised as
follows.
The applicant is a Swedish citizen, born in 1947. He resides
at M., Sweden.
The application concerns the introduction in Sweden of new
legislation imposing a compulsory saving during a certain period: the
1989 Act on Temporary Savings (Lag om tillfälligt sparande).
The legislation on temporary savings was passed by the Swedish
Parliament on 8 June 1989 and published on 16 June 1989 as SFS
1989:474 of the Swedish Law Gazette. The Act entered into force on
1 July 1989. On 18 December 1989 and on 25 April 1991 the Act was
amended in some respects.
The essential provisions of the 1989 Act on Temporary
Savings may be summarised as follows.
The legislation originally affected all Swedish taxpayers, but
was not applicable to the State, municipalities (kommuner), county
councils (landstingskommuner) and church parishes (kyrkliga kommuner).
The savings, to be paid to the State together with the income tax,
were calculated at three per cent of the income tax owed by the
taxpayer. The savings were compulsory and applied to the period 1
September 1989 - 31 December 1990. The savings were to be repaid at
the latest on 30 April the third year following the income year, i.e.
in 1992 and 1993, together with an annual interest at the rate of
seven per cent on amounts up to 1.000 SEK (svenska kronor) concerning
the savings relating to the income year of 1989 and with the same
interest on savings relating to the income year of 1990 up to amounts
of 3.000 SEK. On amounts above these sums the interest rate was 3.5
per cent.
According to the travaux préparatoires, the Report of the
Parliamentary Standing Committee on Finance (Finansutskottets
betänkande) 1988/89: Fi U 30, the reasons for introducing the Act on
Temporary Savings were essentially the following:
(translation)
"The Committee has earlier established that the economic
development is worrying and that there is an obvious risk
for a continuous deterioration of [the Swedish]
international competitiveness. The Committee therefore is
of the opinion that steps must be taken in order to cool
down the overheated economy. The steps taken must be of a
temporary character. A public and perceptible squeeze
should, during a limited period of time, cool down the high
temperature, without reducing the growth of production and
employment in the long run.
As an alternative to the Government's proposal for a
temporary increase of the value added tax, different forms
of a temporary compulsory savings system have been proposed.
As has been suggested in these proposals, an appropriate
increase of savings would reduce the space for
consumption and moderate the trend towards increased
inflation. Compared with an increase of the value added
tax, a temporary savings system has the advantage of
not increasing inflation.
...
A necessary requirement for the squeezes needed is that they
must have an immediate effect on the economy. Next to
different kinds of tax increases, a compulsory savings system
would appear to be the most efficient step in this respect.
A temporary savings system does not lead to an increase in
the burden of taxation. The money will be repaid to the savers
within a certain time.
...
To achieve a sufficient effect and to be as neutral as
possible in respect of the policy of a fair distribution,
there should be few exceptions from the compulsory savings;
both individuals and legal persons should accordingly be
included in the system."
On 18 December 1989 the Act on Temporary Savings was changed
(SFS 1989:1033) in that the compulsory savings during the income year
of 1990 only applied to those who had to save more than 1.000 SEK
during that year. Furthermore, savings relating to the income year of
1989 were to be repaid by 30 June 1990 at the latest if the amount
was less than 300 SEK.
According to the relevant travaux préparatoires, the
Government Bill (Regeringens proposition) 1989/90:50, the reasons for
this exemption from compulsory savings, were essentially that it would
have a small effect on the economic squeeze in general, but a
considerable effect for the low income earners with an income below
approximately 100.000 SEK per year, among them retired people, as they
would not have to save. The responsible minister found that this
would give the legislation on savings a more acceptable profile in
respect of the policy of a fairer distribution of income.
On 25 April 1991 the Act on Temporary Savings was again
amended (SFS 1991:184) in respect of repayment: savings relating to
the income year of 1989 were to be repaid by 31 May 1991 at the latest
and the remaining savings by 28 February 1992.
COMPLAINTS
The applicant complains that the compulsory savings under the
1989 Act on Temporary Savings violate his right to peaceful enjoyment
of his possessions as secured by Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 to the
Convention.
THE LAW
The applicant complains that the introduction in 1989 of
the legislation in Sweden concerning the temporary savings constitutes
a breach of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) to the Convention which
reads:
"Every natural or legal person is entitled to the peaceful
enjoyment of his possessions. No one shall be deprived of his
possessions except in the public interest and subject to the
conditions provided for by law and by the general principles of
international law.
The preceding provisions shall not, however, in any way
impair the right of a State to enforce such laws as it deems
necessary to control the use of property in accordance with the
general interest or to secure the payment of taxes or other
contributions or penalties."
According to the case-law of the European Court of Human
Rights, Article 1 (Art. 1) substance guarantees the right to property.
It comprises "three distinct rules": the first rule, set out in the
first sentence of the first paragraph, is of a general nature and
enunciates the principle of the peaceful enjoyment of property; the
second rule, in the second sentence of the first paragraph, covers
deprivation of possessions and subjects it to certain conditions; the
third rule, stated in the second paragraph, recognises that the
Contracting States are entitled, amongst other things, to control the
use of property by enforcing such laws as they deem necessary in the
general interest. However, these rules are not "distinct" in the
sense of being unconnected: the second and third rules are concerned
with particular instances of interference with the right to peaceful
enjoyment of property and should therefore be construed in the light
of the general principle enunciated in the first rule (Eur. Court
H.R., Tre Traktörer judgment of 7 July 1989, Series A No. 159, pp.
21-22, para. 54, with further references).
In the present case the introduction of the 1989 Act on
Temporary Savings had the effect of forcing taxpayers, including
the applicant, to save amounts corresponding to three per cent of
their income tax and of depriving them of their right to dispose of
this money during a certain period of time. The Commission finds that
this constitutes an interference with the applicant's right to
peaceful enjoyment of his possessions. It considers, however, that
this interference does not fall within the ambit of the second
sentence of the first paragraph, as the savings, although compulsory,
were to be repaid within a certain period of time. Accordingly there
is no deprivation of property within the meaning of Article 1 (Art. 1)
of the Protocol.
The Commission finds that the compulsory savings constituted a
measure of controlling the use of property, to be considered under
the second paragraph of Article 1 (Art. 1), which recognises the right
of the Contracting States to enforce such laws as they deem necessary
for controlling the use of property in accordance with the general
interest. As this provision is to be construed in the light of the
general principle enunciated in the first sentence of the first
paragraph, there must exist a reasonable relationship of
proportionality between the means employed and the aim pursued. In
striking a fair balance between the general interest of the community
and the requirements of the protection of the individual's fundamental
rights, the authorities enjoy a wide margin of appreciation (Eur.
Court. H.R., Allan Jacobsson judgment of 25 October 1989, Series A
No. 163, p. 17, para. 55, with further references).
In the present case, the aim of instituting temporary
compulsory savings was to limit a dangerous trend in the Swedish
economy by reducing consumption and to counteract growing inflation.
The Commission considers this to be a legitimate aim in the general
interest. As regards the proportionality between the interference
with the applicant's property rights and the aim pursued, the
Commission notes that according to the 1989 Act and its amendments the
compulsory savings would not exceed three per cent of the income tax,
would only partly affect those with an income below approximately
100.000 SEK, were limited in time and were to be repaid together with
interest. Having regard to the wide margin of appreciation enjoyed by
the Contracting States, the Commission cannot find that the compulsory
savings by virtue of the 1989 Act were in these circumstances
disproportionate to the aim pursued.
Consequently the interference was justified under the terms of
the second paragraph of Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 (P1-1) to the Convention.
It follows that the application is manifestly ill-founded
within the meaning of Article 27 para. 2 (Art. 27-2) of the Convention.
For these reasons, the Commission by a majority,
DECLARES THE APPLICATION INADMISSIBLE.
Secretary to the Commission President of the Commission
(H.C. KRÜGER) (C.A. NØRGAARD)